ISSN: 2822-0838 Online

Valuation of Benefits of Water Quality and Water Supply to Justify Payments for Ecosystem Services in Mae Sa Watershed, Chiang Mai, Thailand

Oraphan Pradit* and Jirawan Kitchaicharoen
Published Date : 2020-09-01
DOI : https://doi.org/10.12982/CMUJNS.2020.0042
Journal Issues : Number 4, October-December 2020

Abstract For the past two decades, the concept of Payments for Ecosystem Services (PES) has been increasingly used as a market-based instrument to support natural resources and environmental management. Economic evaluation of ecosystem services is an important step for implementing a PES scheme as it helps provide information to stakeholders for their decision-making on payment. This paper aims to evaluate the ecosystem services from upstream village conservation activities in Mae Sa watershed in terms of such water ecosystem services as water quality and water supply. The results revealed that the benefits gained from cleaned water and drought prevention due to conservation activities are worth more than the costs. Moreover, these economic values are the partial economic values of ecosystem services in the watershed and will be used as an effective communication tool to raise concerns among stakeholders over the importance of resource conservation and sustainable resource management practices under the implementation of PES scheme in Mae Sa watershed. 

Keywords: Payments for ecosystem services, Ecosystem services valuation, Damage cost avoided, Choice experiment, Contingent valuation method

INTRODUCTION

Water is a resource basic for and connected with a myriad of human activities, and it is vital for the survival of all living beings.  While it is referenced in different ways by different disciplines, water is a renewable resource in natural resource economics with a growing prevalence of water shortage and water quality problems in many countries and specific areas. In Northern Thailand, particularly in the hilly watershed areas, a water problem is associated with sediments contamination in water bodies, which affects water consumption and cost of water utilization. In 2000, a  land use survey by the Landsat STM program found that 12 million rai of highland forests in the watershed area were destroyed (National Statistical Office, 2005; Tongmee, 2007). It is claimed that deforestation in the north of Thailand has negative impacts on water flow system and increases sedimentation and siltation in reservoirs and watercourses. In addition, the droughts consequential to deforestation had affected the downstream water users (Enter, 1995).

Mae Sa watershed is one basin that has drought effect and water scramble problems because this area has rapidly expanding economic activities involving agriculture, tourism businesses such as resorts, homestays, restaurants, coffee shops, and tourist attractions, government offices and a lot of households. According to a report by the Department of Water Resources (2007), Mae Sa watershed has suffered from water shortages, low-quality water, and water allocation problems (cited by Pramoon, 2008). It also found that many activities in upstream areas used water more than the river capacity. Especially in 2015, a severe drought affected all sectors in Mae Sa watershed. Moreover, households and tourism businesses released wastewater into the river and intensive chemicals were used in agricultural areas without soil and water conservation (Pollution Control Department, 2011). A study of Rungruangwong and Prompati (2007) found that there were 4 from 7 spots that needed to be recovered to the original condition. In terms of chemical water quality, the pH value was low probably due to wastewater from various activities.

Nowadays, the people who live in upstream areas suffer from environmental problems and are aware that they should conserve the natural resources and environment for the next generations. Annually, the upstream villages have been doing the conservation activities such as check dam building, living weir establishment, fire protection, and forest plantation to improve the ecosystem. Nevertheless, the conservation activities have costs and the downstream people have external benefits from such upstream measures as preventing drought, decreasing sedimentation, slowing down the water flow and water retention. Thus, they should pay or support the upstream villages under payments for ecosystem services scheme like that was implemented in Indonesia (1985) under the lake protection program, and Vietnam (1990) under the reforestation program. PES in Mae Sa was introduced by the United States Agency for International Development's: Lowering Emissions in Asia's Forests: USAID – LEAF program in 2011. This is a small project between one water company and one village but most of the stakeholders did not understand this concept and knew more  about Corporate Social Responsibility: CSR (USAID LEAF, 2014). In general, PES implementation is about ecosystem service values in terms of money that the service providers make available to all stakeholders  to increase the awareness of the beneficiaries to provide some supports in return to the ecosystem service providers.

The principle of PES emphasizes provider–based economic approaches (Mauerhofer, et al. 2013) and focuses on “the beneficiary pays principle”. PES will lead to more efficiency of natural resource utilization by economic incentives. It is believed that ecosystem degradation will cause humans to receive fewer benefits from the ecosystem services and will increase the social cost (Wunder, 2007). The people protecting and enhancing the ecosystem service provision will be recognized as ecosystem service providers who make a positive impact on the people living outside the area (beneficiaries) or users of ecosystem services (Steiner et al. 2000). In return, the service users provide the payment to the service providers as incentives to manage their land or natural resources for the purpose of enhancing the ecosystem services. However, the benefit values cannot be clearly described by PES; therefore, the ecosystem service valuation is the information for their decision-making on payment.

This study aims to evaluate the benefits of water by considering the services that occur by changing the water quality and water supply from conservation activities in terms of the economic values of cleaned water and preventing drought. These values were evaluated from water users’ willingness to pay for  water quality improvement and damage cost of drought. Although these economic values are the partial economic values of ecosystem services in the watershed, it can be used as an effective communication tool to raise concerns among stakeholders over the importance of resource conservation. Consequently, PES can generate sustainable resource management in the watershed.

MATERIALS AND METHODS

Site of study

Mae Sa watershed is located in a part of Mae Rim District, Chiang Mai, Thailand. It is a relatively small scale watershed, covering a total area of 142.30 square kilometers or 87,113 rai (1 hectare = 6.25 rai), which  can be divided into 4 parts: forest  53,336.81 rai or 61.23 %, agriculture 19,403.44 rai or 22.27 %, residential area  12,906 rai or 14.82 % and  others  1,466.44 rai or 1.68 % (Land Development Department, 2005; Regional Environment Office 1, 2016). The watershed comprises  upstream and downstream areas. In the upstream areas, there are several villages where most farmers are living and considered as ecosystem service providers in this study. For the downstream areas, there are some farmers, municipality, local entrepreneurs, mineral water company, hotels and resorts which are considered as the service users in  Mae Sa watershed.

Conceptual framework


In Mae Sa watershed, the conservation activities are directly related to three main ecosystem services. In the agricultural ecosystem, the upstream people practice soil conservation  by building terraces on sloping land that could reduce the rate of soil erosion and reduce chemical use that could reduce chemical contaminated in water. In the forest ecosystem, the upstream villagers do the conservation activities by fire protection and forest plantation that could improve water quantity and quality. The last in water ecosystem, the upstream villagers do the conservation activities by check dam building and living weir that could reduce water turbidity and drought. These conservation activities are service in regulating services and provisioning services described by change in water quality and quantity (Millennium Ecosystem Assessment, 2005).

 

 

Figure 1. Conceptual framework.

This study intends to assess these benefits in terms of the economic value of cleaned water and the damage cost of drought. The economic evaluation from water quality improvement is made by willingness to pay method and the water quality which has many levels is studied using choice experiment method. The assessment of damage cost of drought is made using the damage cost avoided that is adapted from intangible flood damage quantification (Lekuthai and Vongvisessomjai, 2001). These benefits of water quality and quantity valuation can be adapted for all of the water users such as agricultural, households and businesses sectors to make their decision making on payment.

Data collection methods

Data collection methods were divided into two parts: 1) water users’ willingness to pay for water quality improvement by means of focus group discussion, key rider interview, and choice experiment questionnaires, 2) damage cost of drought by means of damage cost questionnaires.

Water userswillingness to pay for  water quality improvement. There were 2 levels of data collection; the first was village level data about conservation activities such as materials, labor and total cost collected by interviewing the village leaders. These data were used to design the choices for choice modeling in the questionnaire. The second was water users’ level  data about their willingness to pay for  water quality improvement and factors affecting their willingness to pay.

The number of water users was 19,819 (219 businesses and 19,600 households) (Mae Rim Waterworks Office, 2017). For data collection, quota sampling was used for each population of water users. The total size which was statistically acceptable (P<0.05) was 392 samples (Yamane, 1967). In this study, the number of samples was 454 (376 households and 78 businesses).

Damage cost of drought. The total population in Mae Sa watershed consisted of 8,611 households, 3,170 farmers and 219 businesses (Pong Yang and Mae Ram Sub-district Administrative Organization, 2016). The field survey for costs of drought damage was carried out using structured questionnaires. Quota sampling was used for each population sector. The total sample size was 437 samples which comprised 230 households, 129 farmers and 78 businesses. The intensive fieldwork was carried out in the watershed area between August and September 2017.

Valuation methods

This study implemented two technical approaches including 1) contingent valuation method using choice experiment method by means of allowing people to choose from a menu of options with differing levels of ecosystem services and differing costs (Federal Ministry for Economic Cooperation and Development: BMZ, 2012). Moreover, the specifying relevant attributes in the conditional Logit model and socio-economic factors were used for calculation in Tobit model under the hypothetical situation. 2) Damage cost avoided was used to evaluate the damage cost of drought as in the equations. The value is based on the costs of actions taken to avoid damages if a specific ecosystem service did not exist (Federal Ministry for Economic Cooperation and Development: BMZ, 2012). In this study, the procedure was adapted from intangible flood damage quantification (Lekuthai and Vongvisessomjai, 2001).

Choice experiment method

The attributes and levels of design were used to analyze the suitable activities and value of the willingness to pay for supporting the upstream village conservation activities. The activities consist of reducing the chemical use (to solve the problem of chemicals contamination in the water) and terracing (to solve the problem of soil erosion and sedimentation) in agricultural ecosystem, forest plantation and fire protection (to solve the problem of water quantity and quality) in forest ecosystem and check dam building and living weir establishment (to solve the problem of water turbidity and drought) in water ecosystem.

The hypothetical situation is nowadays there is a group of ‘Community – based conservation and management of natural resources and the environment in Mae Sa watershed’. The upstream villagers (ecosystem services providers) especially spend more time on conservation activities, leading to the loss of opportunity cost of work and rest because all of them have to obey the community rules to participate in the village activities. These conservation activities require the cost, materials, and labor; therefore, the downstream households, resorts, homestays, restaurants and coffee shops (ecosystem services users) who have the benefits from upstream conservation activities or external benefits such as water quality and quantity should also support these activities for sustainability.

Conservation activities in Mae Sa watershed can be divided into 6 types as follows: Activity 1  chemical use reduction, Activity 2 agricultural land terracing, Activity 3  forest plantation, Activity 4  fire protection, Activity 5  check dam building and Activity 6  living weir establishment. Water quality condition can be divided into 4 levels: 1) Turbid water, sediments all year, chemical contamination, 2) Turbid water, sediments only in rainy season, chemical contamination, 3) Clear water, no sediments, chemical contamination and 4) Clear water, no sediments, slight chemical contamination.

Cost of conservation activities and the possible payment of water users was estimated for each activity 1)  Chemical use reduction: the agricultural land in Mae Sa watershed is 7,054 rai. Most of the areas are still farmed with the use of chemicals. However,  40% of these areas are under the practice of using  chemical input at a safe level which will get routine  quality check from the Royal Project. Reducing chemical use thus costs 2,185 baht/rai with the total cost in the watershed of 15,412,990 baht or 777.69 baht/household for those households using water in midstream and downstream areas. From the polluters-pay principle, cost of conservation activities, in this case chemical use reduction, has to be responsible partly by the farmers as they used to have a part to make the environmental damage in the past.  With this cost, however, both farmers and downstream water users will enjoy the benefits of lower exposure to chemicals, lower soil erosion, and more water availability for farming (Nantansen, 2008) . 2) Terracing: total vegetable cultivation area is 3,200 rai. However,   10% or 320 rai of the vegetable land remains farmed without terracing. The terracing costs 6,952 baht/rai, with the total cost in the watershed of 2,224,640 baht or 112.25 baht/household using water in midstream and downstream areas. 3) Forest plantation: there are 10 villages in upstream areas and they are supposed to plant the forest at least 5 rai/village/year. The forest plantation costs 17,730 baht/rai, with the total cost in the watershed of 886,500 baht or 44.73 baht/household using water in midstream and downstream areas. 4) Fire protection: the upstream villages are supposed to increase the forest fire break strips by 10 km/year. The fire protection costs 18,735 baht/km, with the total cost in the watershed of 1,873,500 baht or 94.53 baht/household using water in midstream and downstream areas. 5) Check dam building: the upstream villages are supposed to build the check dam at least 3 units/year. The check dam building costs 7,210 baht/unit, with the total cost in the watershed of 216,300 baht or 10.91 baht/household using water in midstream and downstream areas. 6) Living weir: in 2017, 11 living weirs were built in Mae Sa watershed; thus, in this year at least 10 units should be built. The living weir costs 50,000 baht/unit, with the total cost in the watershed of 500,000 baht or 25.23 baht/household using water in midstream and downstream areas as in Table 1.

Table 1. Attributes and levels

Attribute

Description

Level

Conservation services

Conservation activities that should be supported in terms of payment.

5 levels:

1) Activity 4

2) Activities 3, 4 and 5

3) Activities 3, 4, 5 and 6

4) Activities 2, 3, 4, 5 and 6

5) All activities 1 - 6

Water quality 

Water quality under 4 conditions

4 levels:

1) Turbid water, sediments all year, chemical contamination

2) Turbid water, sediments only in rainy season, chemical contamination

3) Clear water, no sediments, chemical contamination

4) Clear water, no sediments, slight chemical contamination

Individual payment  per year 

The amount of payment that should be paid per year.

6 levels: 

1) 0

2) 100 baht/year

3) 150 baht/year

4) 175 baht/year

5) 300 baht/year

6) 1,070 baht/year

 

The choice experiment is based on attributes and respondents are asked to make a comparison and choose between environmental alternatives characterized by a variety of attributes and levels of attributes (Holmes and Adamowicz, 2003). The record of the choices among the alternatives is used to estimate the respondents’ willingness to pay (WTP) by modeling the probability of the chosen alternative (Stewart and Kahn, 2006; Meyerhoff et al., 2008).

The number of levels in each attribute was analyzed by the full factorial method, giving rise to 120 possible alternatives (5*4*6=120). However, in each alternative, one attribute level may conflict with the other two attribute levels. Thus, the possible alternatives were reduced by the orthogonal design in the SPSS program. Orthogonality was a feasible alternative and had no conflict in the attribute level of 28 alternatives. However, more alternatives were considered too large for respondents to choose from.

The cyclical design method was implemented to group 8 choice sets. Each choice set was divided into 3 alternatives. Alternative 1 was defined as the base case which was a situation that did not change the ecosystem services (current situation). Alternative 2 and 3 were alternatives showing the better ecosystem service change.  Alternative 2 was taken from the first level of 28 alternatives and alternative 3 was based on alternative 2, with a higher level of ecosystem service properties. Therefore, each interviewer was assigned with only 1 block (4 choice sets). The interviewees were requested to choose one alternative from one choice set for the best choice and one alternative from each choice set as exemplified in Figure 2.

Figure 2. Sample of 1 choice set used in the interview.

 

Conditional Logit model. The data about the water users’ willingness to pay for improved water quality were analyzed by the conditional Logit model in Stata program as follows;

Where Vij is the indirect utility of the person i from the selection of alternative j represented by the independent variables as ecosystem service attributes, Aikis the number of conservation activities that the water users i choose, Q1ik is the water quality in level 1 that the water users i choose, Q2ik is the water quality in level 2 that the water users i choose, Q3ik is the water quality in level 3 that the water users i choose, Q4ik is the water quality in level 4 that the water users i choose, Pik is the payment level k that the water users i choose, εi is a random error (average = 0) and  is the coefficient of attributes

Implicit prices. The implicit prices for a change in any attribute can be estimated using the results of the conditional as well as a nested Logit model in a linear form as follows;

                   IP = -ßAttributePayment                                                        (2)

Compensating surplus. The compensating surplus refers to the amount of additional money an agent would need to reach her initial utility after a change in prices, a change in product quality, or the introduction of new products. Compensating variation can be used to find the effect of a price change on an agent's net welfare (Hicks, 1939) expressed as;

                   CS = - (1/ßPayment)(V0 – V1)                                                 (3)

 

Damage cost of drought equation. Drought affects all parts of the environment and communities. Many different drought impacts are often grouped as environmental, social and economic impacts (National Drought Mitigation Center, 2017). The environmental impacts are the loss of plants’ and animals’ food and the destruction of wildlife habitat. The social impacts affect people’s health and safety. Moreover, the economic impacts are impacts of drought that cost people (or business) money. There are a few different economic impacts of each sector as follows;

Agricultural sector: farmers may lose money from no cultivation and may have to spend more money on water supply or drought may destroy their crops.

Household sector: drought may affect their daily lives and households may lose their income or have to seek for water to use.

Business sector: businesses may lose income from stopping or decreasing services or may have to invest in the water supply.

The equation was based on the  drought damages between 2015 and 2017 following Logar et al. (2012).  The damage cost of drought is calculated from the sum of damage cost (direct cost from drought such as loss of yield), prevention cost (cost for preventing drought such as buying the tank) and avoidance cost (cost from no cultivation). Moreover, the level of drought damage is also considered and classified into 4 levels, i.e., no effect (0), low effect (1), moderate effect (2) and high effect (3) and presented in percentage of sample and average cost.

Value of drought loss reduction = Damage Cost + Prevention Cost + Avoidance Cost

This equation was developed to find out the total cost of drought damages in agricultural, household and business sectors in the watershed areas. It was adapted from intangible flood damage quantification (Lekuthai and Vongvisessomjai, 2001). 

                              (4)

                                                                 (5)

                                             (6)

                               (7)

Where     DCA      is the damage cost of agriculture (baht)

               DAi        is the damaged area of crop i (rai)

               DYi       is the damaged yield of crop i (kg/rai)

               Pi           is the  price of crop i (baht/kg)

               Ni         is the non-cultivated areas due to drought of crop i (rai)

              EYi        is the expected yield when crop i was cultivated (baht/rai)

              TVCi      is the total variable cost of crop i (baht/rai)

             W      is the total value of additional water bought to solve the drought problem (baht)

             I        is the other investment cost to solve or prevent drought problem (baht)

             DCH       is the damage cost of household (baht)

             AFj         is the number of days that activity j got affected by drought (days)

             Cj           is the opportunity cost of activity j (baht/day)

             DCB        is the damage cost of business (baht)

             SFk         is the number of days that service k got affected by drought (days)

             SDk         is the decrease in service k (person, room or table per day)

             Pk           is the price of entry, room or average income of service k (baht/person, room

                            or table)

             SSk         is the number of days that service k had to stop due to drought (days)

             TDC        is the total damage cost of drought (baht)

             ADCAl     is the average damage cost of agriculture at the level l, l is 1, 2, 3 or 4 (baht/farm)

             ADCHl     is the average damage cost of households of level l (baht/household)

            ADCBl      is the average damage cost of business of level l (baht/business)

        Pop1l,2l,3l    is the population of water user group 1 (agriculture), 2 (household) or 3 (business) that had drought effects at the level l (household)

     

RESULTS

Water userswillingness to pay for improved water quality

The conditional Logit model was used when the base alternative of water quality had no change and the base alternative of payment was zero. The calculation from this model resulted in the indirect utility function from the change of attributes.

It was found that almost all attributes were statistically significant at the confidence level of 95%. Implicit price or marginal value is the monetary value from the change of one attribute level, calculated from the coefficient of attributes and the coefficient of payment as shown in Table 2. The addition of 1 conservation activity could increase the marginal value to 91.56 baht/activity. The change from base situation to turbid water, sediments all year and chemical contamination could reduce the marginal value to -247.19 baht. The change from base situation to turbid water, sediments only in rainy season and chemical contamination could reduce the marginal value to -110.58 baht. The change from base situation to clear water, no sediments and chemical contamination could increase the marginal value to 29.15 baht. The change from base situation to clear water, no sediments and slight chemical contamination could increase the marginal value to 300.75 baht. The compensating surplus is the compensating payment from changing ecosystem services that the water users can get the same satisfaction or is the difference between the water users’ willingness to pay and the price that consumers actually pay, as shown in Table 2. 

Table 2. Implicit price and compensating surplus of attributes.

Attributes

Implicit price (baht)

Compensating surplus (baht)

Conservation activities

Turbid water, sediments all year and chemical contamination

Turbid water, sediments only in rainy season and chemical contamination

Clear water, no sediments, and chemical contamination

Clear water, no sediments, and slight chemical contamination

   91.56

-247.19

 

-110.58

 

  29.15

 

300.75

  91.56

-219.31

 

-82.71

 

   1.27

 

272.87

From the Table 2, the addition of 1 conservation activity could increase the compensating surplus to 91.56 baht/activity. The change from base situation to turbid water, sediments all year and chemical contamination could reduce the compensating surplus to -219.31 baht. The change from base situation to turbid water, sediments only in rainy season and chemical contamination could reduce the compensating surplus to -82.71 baht. The change from base situation to clear water, no sediments and chemical contamination could increase the compensating surplus to 1.27 baht. The change from base situation to clear water, no sediments and slight chemical contamination could increase compensating surplus to 272.87 baht.

The alternatives that the water users were willing to pay were evaluated by representing the attributes and levels of attributes in the probability equation derived from the conditional Logit model. The result of this method was the probability for each alternative to be selected.

The top of alternatives selected by water users was alternative 16 with the probability of 0.2092511. The marginal compensating surplus is used to evaluate the marginal willingness to pay for selected alternatives.

The marginal willingness to pay of each alternative can be used to evaluate the water users’ willingness to pay per household. The willingness to pay was 459.07 baht/household.

The willingness to pay for water users per household can be used to evaluate the total willingness to pay for conserving natural resources and environment to improve water quality in Mae Sa watershed. The total willingness to pay was 9,098,308.33 baht per year. 

The analysis of socio-economic factors affecting the willingness to pay

The Tobit model was used to estimate the maximum likelihood estimation (MLE) by setting the lower bound at 0 and the upper bound at 1.

     WTP = f (Gender, Age, User, Income, Member, Source, Join, Frequency, Support)

Where:  WTP         is the indirect utility of the person i from the selection of alternative j represented by the independent variables as ecosystem

                            service attributes

            Gender      is the gender of tourists (1 if male, 0 if female)

            Age           is the age of tourists (years)

            User          is the water user (1 if business, 0 if household)

            Income      is the water users’ income per month (baht)

            Member     is the number of household members or business service users

            Source       is the water source (1 if  others, 0 if plumbing)

            Join           is having joined the conservation activities (1 if yes, 0 if never)

           Frequency is the frequency of joining the conservation activities (time/year)

           Support     is support given to the conservation activities (1 if yes, 0 if no)

           i                is a sample of i

The analysis showed that the chi-square values were significant at 99 and 90 percent. There were 3 independent variables that influenced the willingness to pay of water users, which were income per month, participation in the conservation activities and support for the conservation activities.

Based on the coefficient and the marginal effect (Table 3), the increase of income per month by 100 baht could increase the willingness to pay by 0.034 %. The participation in and the support for the conservation activities could increase the willingness to pay by 0.106 % and 1.00% respectively. Those samples ever participated in and supported for the conservation activities could increase their willingness to pay.

 

Table 3.   The analysis of factors affecting the willingness to pay of users in Mae Sa watershed.

Variable

Coefficient

Standard error of coefficient

Marginal effect

Standard error of marginal effect

Gender

Age

User

Income

Member

Source

Join

Frequency

Support

-0.0037135

-0.0007057

0.0102333

0.0003386*

-0.0003716

-0.0518832

0.1062635***

-0.0018062

1.009256***

0.0272757

0.0010223

0.0532363

0.0001777

0.001063

0.0395505

0.0384376

0.0081829

0.1245056

-0.00371

-0.00071

0.01023

0.00034*

-0.00037

-0.05186

0.10622***

-0.00181

1.00881***

0.02726    

0.00102    

0.05321     

0.00018    

0.00106    

0.03953   

0.03842    

0.00818    

0.12443    

Note: ***, **, * ==> Significance at 1%, 5%, 10% level.

 

Damage cost of drought

The impact of drought in the agricultural sector was calculated from 129 samples. Droughts during 2015 -2017 had effects at the different levels. Farmers in upstream areas got the highest effect in prevention, avoidance and damage costs with the average cost being 15,602, 28,432 and 45,520 baht/farm, respectively.

For the household sector, the damage costs of drought were presented in terms of preventing cost and damage cost from 230 samples. Households in downstream areas experienced the highest effect on the average from preventing and damage cost with 8,559 and 3,066 baht/household, respectively.

The drought seems to affect the business sector less than the agricultural sector as most business samples (74.79%) did not get an effect from drought. Business sector had prevention, avoidance and damage cost with the average of 17,325, 12,625 and 13,111 baht/firm, respectively.

Finally, the percentages and average costs of each sector were used with the total population to calculate the total damage cost of droughts in Mae Sa watershed (Table 4).

 

Table 4. Total damage cost of drought in  Mae Sa watershed during 2015-2017.

 

Type of water users

Sample

Total population in the watershed in each sector

Total damage cost of drought

(baht)

% of total samples

Average damage cost (baht/sample)

Agriculture

- No effect

- Low effect

- Moderate effect

- High effect

 

67.44

10.85

13.17

8.53

 

0

5,769

15,279

58,683

 

871

140

168

110

 

0

807,660

2,566,872

6,455,130

Sum

100.0

79,731

1,292

9,829,662

Household

- No effect

- Low effect

- Moderate effect

- High effect

 

70.00

8.26

14.78

6.96

 

0

815

3,462

23,947

 

6,028

711

1,273

599

 

0

579,465

4,407,126

14,344,253

Sum

100.0

27,701

8,611

19,330,844

Business

- No effect

- Low effect

- Moderate effect

- High effect

 

74.36

2.56

11.54

11.54

 

0

4,067

12,379

52,242

 

163

6

25

25

 

0

24,402

309,475

1,306,050

Sum

100.0

68,688

219

1,639,927

Sum of three sectors

100.0

176,120

10,122

30,800,433

The average cost of drought per year (baht)

 

58,707

 

-

 

10,266,811


The average damage cost of drought per sample is used to assess the total damage cost of drought in Mae Sa watershed. The results show that in the agricultural sector, there could be about 110 farmers experiencing an extreme effect of 58,683 baht/farm and the total damage cost of drought in this sector could be about 9,829,662 baht. For the household sector, 599 households possibly got an extreme effect of 23,947 baht/household and the total damage could cost about 19,586,717 baht. Whereas the business sector seems to get the lowest effect of drought in the watershed, only 56 from 219 businesses in the watershed possibly encountered the extreme effect of 52,242 baht/business and the total damage cost could be about 1,639,927 baht. The total damage cost of drought of all three sectors could be 30,800,433 baht. As the result, the damage cost of drought could be reduced up to 10,266,811 baht/year if the droughts in  Mae Sa watershed can be prevented or reduced from supporting conservation activities to be done by the upstream villagers.

DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION

This paper presents the ecosystem service valuation from the upstream conservation activities which affect water quality and water supply. These values are the partial economic value which actually contains the values of water, soil and forest. The economic values of water presented in terms of damage cost of drought loss reduction and the value of cleaned water. The damage cost of drought loss reduction was 10,266,811 baht per year. It is assumed that conservation activities can prevent drought by 100%. However, if the drought in the area can be prevented only 50%, it is still considered high value. Moreover, these damage costs were calculated based on the last 3 years’ information but the conversation activities in the upstream areas can have direct consequences for ecosystem services and last longer than 3 years. The total willingness to pay of water users in Mae Sa watershed was 9,098,308 baht. Thus, the economic value of water quality and quantity were 19,365,119 baht per year. The results from factors affecting the willingness to pay were the water users’ income, the water users’ ever participating in and supporting conservation activities whereas the latter two factors could increase their willingness to pay. This information can be used to implement PES in Mae Sa watershed by arranging a PES meeting forum and inviting all stakeholders to participate.

As the results of this study, the economic value can be used to present the benefits from ecosystem services to all stakeholders in the watershed to increase their awareness to conserve the natural resources and environment in the areas. Moreover, these economic values can be used as information for the downstream users to make a decision on payment in PES scheme for supporting the upstream villagers to increase their conservation activities. Therefore, the government should make the policy to generate PES continually.

REFERENCES

Department of Water Resources. 2007. The Mae Sa basin. Baseline water resources storage in the area. Available from: http://www.water.
go.th/basindata/maesa.index

Enters, T. 1995. The economics of land degradation and resource conservation in Northern Thailand. Institute of Southeast Asian Studies,Singapore: 90-110.

Federal Ministry for Economic Cooperation and Development: BMZ. 2012. Ecosystem service valuation approaches: the economics of desertification. land degradation and drought.

Hicks, J.R. 1939. Value and capital: An inquiry into some fundamental principles of economic theory. London: Clarendon Press.

Holmes, T.P., Adamowicz, W.L. 2003. Attribute-based methods. United States Department of Agriculture. Available from: https://www.fs.usda.gov/
treesearch/pubs/6313
.

Land Development Department. 2005. Academic documents of the master plan for land use planning to prevent soil deterioration and increase the potential economic crops as well as soil and water conservation. Bangkok: Ministry of Agriculture and Cooperatives.

Lekuthai, A., Vongvisessomjai, S. 2001. Intangible flood damage quantification. Journal of Water Resources Management15: 343–362. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1014489329348

Logar,  I., and Van den Bergh, J.C.J.M. 2012. Damages and policies for drought mitigation and adaptation: review and recommendations. Water Resources Management: an International Journal. 27(6): 1707-1720. https://doi.org/ 10.1007/s11269-012-0119-9.

Mauerhofer, V., Hubacek, K., and Coleby, A. 2013. From polluter pays to provider gets: distribution of rights and costs under payments for ecosystem services. Ecology and Society 18(4): 41. https://doi.org/10.5751/ES-06025-180441

Mae Rim Waterworks Office. 2017. Number of water users. Available from : https://www.pwa.co.th/province/branch/5510214

Meyerhoff, J.R., Liebe, U., and Hartje, V. 2008. Benefits of biodiversity enhancement of nature-oriented silviculture: evidence from two choice

experiments in Germany. Journal of Forest Economics. 15: 37–58. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfe.2008.03.003

Millennium Ecosystem Assessment. 2005. Ecosystems and human well-being: synthesis. Washington, DC: Island Press.

Nantansen, G. 2008. The willingness to accept soil and water conservation of farmers in upper Mae Sa watershed, Chiang Mai province [Master’s Thesis]. Department of Agricultural Economics, Faculty of Agriculture: Chiang Mai University.

National Drought Mitigation Center. 2017. Types of drought impacts.  Available from:http://drought.unl.edu/DroughtforKids/HowDoesDroughtAffectOurLives/TypesofDroughtImpacts.aspx

National Statistics Office. 2005, 2012. Agricultural statistics of Thailand. Office of Agricultural Economics. Bangkok: Ministry for Agricultural and Cooperatives.

Pramoon, N. 2008. The willingness to pay for water supply of downstream farmers in Mae Sa watershed, Chiang Mai Province [Master’s Thesis]. Department of Agriculture Economics: Chiang Mai University.

Pollution Control Department. 2011. Wastewater problems. Available from: http://www.pcd.go.th/info_serv/plan_strategy.html

Pong Yang and Mae Ram Sub-district Administrative Organization. 2016. Population Number.

Regional Environment Office 1. 2016. Ecological assessment: assessing condition and trend of ecosystem service of Mae sa watershed, Chiang Mai Province. The Completed report. p. 23-25.

Rungruangwong, W., and Prompati, S.G. 2007. River ecosystem monitoring. water quality and diversity of benthic animals. The Mae Sa River Doi Suthep-Pui National Park, Mae Rim District, Chiang Mai Province  [Master’s Thesis]. Faculty of Science: Chiang Mai University.

Steiner, F., Blair, J., Mcsherry, L., Guhathakurta, S., Marruffo, J., and Holm, M.  2000. A watershed at a watershed: the potential for environmentally sensitive area protection in the upper San Pedro Drainage Basin (Mexico and USA). Landscape and Urban Planning 49(3-4): 129 – 148. https://doi. org/10.1016/S0169-2046(00)00062-1

Stewart, S., and Kahn. J.R. 2006. An introduction to choice modeling for non-market valuation. In: Alberini, A., Kahn, J.R., Editors, Handbook on Contingent Valuation. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

Tongmee, A. 2007. Upland conservation and management: the report of biodiversity, forests and wildlife. Available from: http://chmthai.
onep.go.th/chm/mountain/status/mana_utai.pdf.

USAID. 2014. Payment for ecosystem services pilot implementation in Mae Sa-Kog Ma Man and Bioshere Reserve. USAID Lowering Emissions in Asia’s Forests (USAID LEAF).

Wunder, S. 2007. The efficiency of payments for environmental services in tropical conservation. Conservation Biology 21(1): 48 – 58. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1523-1739.2006.00559.x

Yamane, T. 1967. Statistics: an introductory analysis. 2nd ed. New York: Harper and Row.

 

 

Oraphan Pradit1* and Jirawan Kitchaicharoen2

 1Agricultural Systems Management Program, Center for Agricultural Resource System Research, Faculty of Agriculture, Chiang Mai University, Chiang Mai 50200, Thailand

2Division of Agricultural Economics, Department of Agricultural Economy and Development, Faculty of Agriculture, Chiang Mai University, Chiang Mai 50200, Thailand

 

*Corresponding author. E-mail: mimaggie38@hotmail.com


Total Article Views


Article history:

Received: April 10, 2019

Revised: August 24, 2019

Accepted: October 28, 2019